Marshall-Lerner Condition

Can the depreciation of the currency increase net exports? This depends on the price elasticities of demand (PED) for exports (PEDX )and imports (PEDM). When the currency is depreciated, exports decline in the foreign currency price while imports increase in the domestic currency price. For net exports to increase, and for the trade balance of the exporting country to improve, the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for exports + the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for imports must exceed 1, which is represented by the Marshall-Lerner condition (MLC):


|PEDX| + |PEDM| > 1

Because the quantities demanded declines with increases in prices, price elasticity is negative, so absolute values are used.

Whether a lower foreign exchange rate will improve the trade balance of an exporting country can be more simply considered by noting that the total revenue of exports must increase more than any increase in total expenses paid for imports:

(Export Revenue − Import Expenses) before Depreciation > (Export Revenue − Import Expenses) after Depreciation

To see why MLC must hold, it will be illustrative to use extreme values. When considering the price elasticities of exports and imports, it is important to remember that the price that the exporter receives in its domestic currency per exported item is the same, regardless of the exchange rate. If the domestic currency is depreciated with respect to the foreign currency, then the foreign customer pays a lower price in terms of its own currency. This increases the quantity of exports sold, so the exporter earns its price in domestic currency multiplied by the quantity sold. But, an increase in export revenue must exceed any increase in import expense, for the balance of trade to move in favor of the exporting country. This will be easier to understand with an illustration.

Consider 2 exporters, one in the United States (US) and one in the United Kingdom (UK). The American exporter exports American widgets to the UK, while the British exporter exports British widgets to the US. This is the only trade between the 2 countries. Now suppose that the exchange rate for American dollars ($) and British sterling pounds (£) is initially 1 to 1, or $1 = £1. Let assume the following initial facts:

Assume now that the US dollar is depreciated by 50%, so that $2 = £1, but the elasticity of the American export is 1, meaning that the quantity sold in Britain is doubled with a halving of price, and that British imports are perfectly inelastic, meaning that the quality does not change with a doubling of price in the US, so elasticity = 0:

Note that, even though the revenue of the American exporter has doubled to $40,000, it still only equals the £20,000 after considering the new exchange rate, so trade is still balanced, so:
MLC = |PEDX| + |PEDM| = 1 + 0
In this case, only if |PEDX| > 1 − |PEDM|, will the balance of trade move in favor of the United States, and the more that |PEDX| exceeds 1 − |PEDM|, more positive that the balance of trade will move in favor of the exporter. If it is less than 1, then the balance of trade will move in favor of the other country, which in this case is the UK.

If |PEDX| > 1 − |PEDM|, then a lower foreign exchange rate will cause the quantity of exported items to increase more than enough to offset any increase in import expense, thus improving the trade balance for the exporting country. But since PEDM < PEDX, the amount paid for imports will either not increase as much as the increase in revenue from exports or import expenses might even decline. However, if PEDM > PEDX, then a decrease in the foreign exchange rate for the exporting country will cause total revenue from exports to be less than the change in expenses paid for imports, thus increasing the trade deficit for the exporting country. On the other hand, if PEDX = PEDM, then elasticity is unitary, so the exporting country's trade balance will be unchanged.

Revenue Differences between the Demand Elasticities for Domestic and Exported Products

As illustrated in the above example, the key to understanding the MLC is to realize that revenue changes differently for a product between domestic and export markets, when the price changes, even when the price elasticity of demand is the same for both markets, and the price changes by the same percentage in both countries. For instance, consider a company that sells a widget with unit elasticity in both domestic and foreign markets. (How to Calculate Demand Elasticity) Unit elasticity means that if the company halves the price of the widget in its domestic market, then it will double the quantity sold. However, the total revenue received by the company will be the same, because it is selling double the quantity at half the price, so the lower price per widget offsets the increase in quantity, resulting in no change in revenue.

But for an exported product, the revenue calculation differs for the exporter. If the foreign product price is half because the exchange rate of the foreign currency increased 50%, then the product is half the price in the foreign currency, but the exporter still receives the same price in domestic currency for each exported widget as before the change in foreign exchange rates. So, if the exported product has unit elasticity in the foreign country, then the 50% reduction in the foreign price will lead to a doubling of sales in the foreign country. This doubles the revenue received by the exporter.

Diagram of the J-Curve that depicts the lag between the currency depreciation of a country and the improvement in its trade balance.

J-Curve

However, even if currency depreciation does improve a country's trade balance, the effect will not be immediate; there is a time lag when the trade balance actually worsens until it starts getting better again, because it is commonly observed that import prices rise faster than export prices fall in other country, with a resulting lag in change of quantities sold of the exported items in the other country. This causes the balance of trade to worsen due to the higher import prices before it gets better.

Another explanation often advanced for the J-curve is that short-term elasticities are less elastic than long-term elasticities. Hence, when the currency is depreciated, import expenses quickly increase, because it takes time to find less expensive substitutes, while the export revenue increases less quickly because of the short-term relative inelasticity.

The J-Curve depicts the lag between the currency depreciation of a country and the improvement in its trade balance.

  1. Depreciation occurs.
  2. Trade balance worsens as prices of imports rises before the prices of exports falls.
  3. Trade balance improves as the effects of changes in the exchange rate propagate through the economies of both countries.

Note that the J-curve will be more noticeable when there is a substantial depreciation over a brief time, such as when the government suddenly depreciates its currency. However, the usual case is that exchange rates fluctuate slowly, moving up and down as they trend up or down, much like stock prices. In these cases, the J-curve may be much diminished or even nonexistent.